Dropbox or Netflix? – Is there a fiscal cliff in companies digitization strategies?

I have both a Dropbox and a Netflix subscription. The one I think about most is Netflix. It’s a fixed monthly fee that I know I can manage if my situation changes – and indeed have done – taking a break from Netflix for a while and using another streaming service, running two in parallel for a while and also canceling both for a while. It fits my mental image of what I think is best about the digital world. Flexible, get to see what I want, when I want – pay for use and stop when I want. But then there is my dropbox account. Maybe running at a 10th of the yearly cost of streaming services or less. However, I have spent a long time making sure dropbox is my safe haven for my family photos and videos. My backup of backups. Now running at family photos dating back to early 2000! Clearly, I could change in theory and it’s a flexible subscription if my circumstances changes. But it’s really a fiction. I won’t be dropping this subscription any time soon. There are too many lock-in points to make this anything but the most painful transition and I sincerely hope that I can always pay this amount and Dropbox does not go on a systematic price increase with me – because I fear I will have to say yes.

This leads me to wonder about what happens if my Dropbox lock-in becomes the dominate situation in the way we pay for our digital economy – particularly from a company perspective. What does this mean? Are companies at risk of creating a debt bubble, locking in uncompetitive cost structures and reducing profitability, as they accelerate their transformation towards the “digital economy”?

These are personal opinions and in no way reflect the situation or opinions of the company I work for.

The trigger for asking myself this question came from a UK Bank of England warning last month that a potential new debt bubble was emerging in the UK around personal debt, with one of the main drivers, this time, not being housing, but Personal Contract Plans for cars – or leasing to you and me.

A long way from the digital economy maybe.

However, my first reaction was to draw a connection – because car leasing – for me – seems a bit like my Netflix account. It gives limited financial exposure, ability to be flexible and walk away after a shorter period, rather than invest in an expensive asset, ability to pay per use (of a sort) with all risks taken care of, ability to change cars (technology) as they change on the market and so on.

Now someone, that I must admit knows a hell of a lot more about these things than I do, was saying something that felt like the opposite to my intuition. Car leasing could lead to more risk. Not less risk. And even a bubble. Clearly this is something to do with penetration – when PCP’s were not the main form of financing, no flags were raised – it is a problem because it is becoming a dominant model to pay for cars. So what’s going on? and can we use this case as a framework to look at what is happening in companies who are moving to a digital model? (which is most companies I know of).

Several elements were raised in the discussions around the Bank of England announcement – all being risks increasing rather than direct problems here and now. So here goes – I will take some elements gleaned from some articles and news items around the UK emerging risk in personal debt, and then attempt to take these over to the world of the digital economy and digital transformation that companies are now undertaking.

From the not so deep reading around the announcement on car leasing leading to personal debt, I have picked up three types of risk.

1) People lock away money into a higher fixed monthly payment, and the flexibility promised becomes a fiction.

Once in this system, a lot of people do not build up the capital to make the down-payments for loans to buy a car and PCPs offer a way to avoid large down-payments. This essentially means people must stay in the leasing system. Flexibility becomes a fiction (people must have a car) and a person becomes committed to a high fixed cost that cannot be varied. At best maybe they can move to lease a smaller car next leasing round.

This is different to when you buy your own car. The financing / debt part is a lower fixed outgoing – often a reasonable down payment is demanded with slightly more credit checks – and a lot of people will reach points during their ownership where they pay it all off and free up the money to other stuff. People are also able to some extent vary the monthly outgoings (and implicitly vary the risks) over time periods. Remember that time you skipped a year of “official services” and went without, or did not follow the garage advise buy new tires or whatever was recommended because it was not urgent. You could vary the commitment without giving up the car. Also, if pressed you could change your monthly outgoings quickly. Maybe sell and buy a similar car but older and with more mileage, using one to put a down payment on the other and cut immediate monthly outgoings.

2) People “over-pay”

The leasing structure encourages that we take the slightly better option – as they buy large numbers in bulk and for specific models / options offer very attractive monthly fees, without the person really feeling how much additional risk is being taken on, for what at the time seems an affordable small increase in fixed monthly outgoing. A big driver to this is that access to money is cheap – so that people are encouraged to do this and finance is almost always given.

3) People are still exposed to market risk – and the risk increases.

Most leasing build in some connection to the market changes to manage risk – in the PCP case it is tied to assumptions that the second-hand market prices for cars do not change a lot. If they change – people in the leasing will have to change their payments or maybe need to find additional money to cover the difference in order move to the next 3-year leasing. The system becomes sensitive, rather than robust, to particular kinds of changes – and often builds in its own pyramid effect and fulfills its own weak point. In this case if all move to leasing, the overall uptake rate for new cars goes up, and for a while drives new car growth. However, at the same time builds up a potential large negative correction of the second-hand car market as the market for these cars is undermined.

I am sure there are different leasing structures that help a little with different risks- but the end result is that a lot of people are locked into a specific form of financing that demands a fixed amount is taken out of people’s finances continuously with no break. These people must have a car, and can end up in a situation they must continue a leasing approach, and if suddenly they need to vary their fixed amount for other reasons, they are unable to. At this point the leasing becomes a personal debt issue and will play out as such in their lives. If everyone does it, and the system becomes very sensitive to specific type of correction (that the system itself will possibly trigger), then it’s a bubble that can burst.

Again, as always, a lot of simplification in this – but I think enough to set a frame to think about digital economy, and companies transitioning to this economy.

So, moving to this area – there are many business models in the digital economy – but that is not the point. The question is, are there any taking over as the dominant form, and does this have some of the same characteristics we see in the Personal Debt case above. If so, are we building up a company fiscal cliff?

If I look around at the business models that seem to be most in use in the company space – there are not a lot. The dominant approach seems to be a modified pay-per-use IT cloud solutions based offering to enable the company to be part of the digital economy -and its everywhere throughout a company. In its IT infrastructure, in its product/service sales systems and even in the actual core product/service offering itself. In terms of infrastructure, process or service, the cost is often tied to number of people using the service (think Salesforce). It might also be products/services a company uses to carry out functions to support for example R&D – or maybe storage space in data centers, then amount of times services are used or quantity used may be the payment metric (think Autodesk world of simulation and other tools with their token system for tool usage), or maybe its supporting sales transactions themselves , for example an e-commerce billing system like Fastspring – then it’s some % charge per sale amount like a credit card cost – often on top of a credit card cost if purchase is with a credit card (so a pay per use on turnover). Now we also see emergence of breakthrough tech. – for example a sensor that for certain types of applications embeds all that’s needed for a company to extend its product to sense more and transport that data to a cloud environment – but these companies are not selling the sensor to other companies as a variable cost direct material component – instead they sell the data cloud info as a pay-per-use / subscription type service and give the sensor as part of the fee.

The payment structures are clearly varied and build in discounts – but it’s likely to be a combination of a monthly base fee + a usage payment model + some enterprise discount as the usage parameter grows. All this looks basically like a kind of leasing set up to me – and one, like the PCP above, that is dominating and growing fast. This, of course, is not surprising as it fits the value selling “Netflix” mental model of what the cloud and internet is about, which is the one I think we naturally carry round in our minds – ensuring flexible “agile” company structure – scalable with use, avoid heavy maintenance, keep updated with latest functionality in the prices and so on.

There are other models like freemium and still a traditional standalone cost then fees to upgrade, as well as companies that basically build their own in-house solutions – but clearly standalone is the “traditional” approach that is being challenged and seems to be losing out. Freemium seems to end up looking like the pay per use type scenario in that any company starts with the free element to play with the system, enabling the seller to get in, then when the company decides to use it systematically they pay the subscription tied to usage – so back to a subscription / usage model. Basically, this for me is like test driving cars before buying – clearly you don’t expect to pay for that. The do-it-yourself model is definitely seen as “not a good idea” ( specialist in-house solutions based on a few experts, heavy unique maintenance , high risk to fail to update at pace needed etc ) unless you are one of the players selling the IT cloud based enterprise system to companies. These guys interestingly, often build their business models up with heavy doses of core open source offerings, or make deals with each other – so are often not tied to the same business and hence financial model as they are selling to the rest of us. 

So, let’s try and use the above car leasing as a framework of tests to see if there is an issue in the world of companies moving to digital / Cloud based enterprises. My focus is companies undergoing a transition where they are moving both underlying IT infrastructure and usually also product offerings to be cloud based – often called digitalisation or moving to the cloud based economy. Usually these companies have some strong business model based around selling one-off products and or services – so will have strong focus on Profit & Loss and Balance sheets , typically around turnover, contribution margins, fixed costs, EBIT, CAPEX, Cash Flow and so on.

The first test is – are we locking ourselves into a fixed monthly outgoing that is high AND is the flexibility to change or vary this an illusion?

For me personally this is my Netflix subscription vs my dropbox subscription argument. Are companies buying cloud services that lock them in? As far as I can see, in my limited experience, companies play with a lot of these services, but eventually decide for reasons of efficiency, to scale up a few across the company. These immediately are configured to the companies needs and essentially the company locks itself in. It seems like its Dropbox all the way to me. As the picture at the top of the article shows – we are not talking about one or two systems, processes or value add elements, but many packages. Each one seems a reasonable fixed cost to take on board, but quickly they add up to a large fixed cost to the company. Going out every month. So, high fixed costs. I would love to know what company IT budgets look like as the company moves to a cloud based approach, and how much the fixed expenditure on software subscription license jumps – but I am sure it’s a big jump – a bit like moving to leasing. Of course, the total cost argument is used – less people in maintenance and so on – but bottom line – jump in fixed cost outgoings.

The second part of the first test is flexibility. The mitigating idea is that these cloud-based product/services we pay for become more like our direct material variable cost – we gain flexibility as the company situation changes. Here to some extent I agree, but I don’t see this like the variable cost of a product. It’s something like a blended fixed/variable cost that impacts the profit and loss, as well as the balance sheet, tying up cash.

It is tied to usage drivers so eventually there will be a cost reaction as company’s sales and traditional fixed costs (usually people and related costs) change. But the lock-ins are big – discounts are built-in that mean it’s not a linear reaction. There are many different cost drivers built in (as mentioned above), so changes to monthly fees are slow and not immediate and you may have to fall a long way before you can impact the fixed monthly outgoing. It is a tax that is likely spread across turnover, number of people, amount of usage of the service (like storage or simulations) that indirectly and weakly link to changes a company might see in the market. So for example, reducing the workforce will have an impact on usage tied to people – but no guarantee it’s a simple and quick response as only part of total monthly fee ties to people usage as driver and the discount likely means a big headcount reduction is needed to move the needle . All this means slow reaction that probably will be way too little, too late to help any quarterly or even yearly changes in the company’s fortunes. So not totally rigid – but not good.

What about flexibility to change? the car service skipped or buy a cheaper used model idea from car ownership? This also seems not possible. If you have a drop in contribution or drop in profitability or whatever – you’re not going to be able to look to your cloud costs to help you out. There is no time out available on the fixed outgoings and no sell and buy a cheaper model.

In summary to the first “Car Leasing Bubble” test. Yes, to fixed cost outgoings increasing, a pretty weak argument that the outgoings will scale costs up and down over time, based on usage, and Yes to no flexibility in the leasing model itself to “skip a service”. You’re on the hook.

So on to the second test – do we buy too much – or “upgrade” to a car we would normally not buy. Well in terms of the availability of cheap capital – my impression is that if we think that people at an individual level have access to cheap money – that’s nothing compared to what companies with reasonable balance sheets can access. Of course, companies tend to think a lot more about spending money – so tend to be much more careful. However, the cloud based systems we are talking about , for me, seem to be premium product only across the board. The only product available is the one that has all the functions you can think of, so that it can configure to a wide range of industries and applications, so you always are buying a premium package with many features you will never use. In addition the product will usually belong to a family of modules that you are also encouraged to buy. Result seems to be we always pay for the trade up model. So the second test also seems to indicate a problem.

Lastly does this cost model and all these many systems we are now paying monthly fees to, expose us to a greater market risk, or even worse actually help accelerate the risk. This is clearly not so simple to answer as the car leasing situation. 

One risk is clear at the company level, and that is companies are tied to a high monthly outgoing that is not so flexible. This exposes companies to rigidity rather than flexibility in their cost structure, making them less, not more, able to adjust as their fortunes vary in the market. This will be amplified if the company business is around one-off sales and is transitioning – as it has no financial language or performance systems to offset this increasing fixed outgoings against normal quarterly variations in the markets and the resulting variations in margins, and other targets it sets itself.

Another risk that is at a market level, is bankruptcy of the IT enterprise system supplier. This will happen to some. Given the fact that many of these systems end up being like my Dropbox – this becomes a company critical issue to the companies using the system. A clear warning trend for this risk will be that especially larger companies will go for vendors that are “too big to fail”. Like Microsoft or Salesforce or SAP, escalating the problem of tying a huge percentage of larger companies in the hands of a few platform players. This is because of my Dropbox effect – second sourcing or similar tactics that are the mainstay of risk mitigation by purchasing are no longer possible. Clearly this consolidation effect does build up a potential for a bubble – in that shocks to a few key vendor players can have an over proportional effect on companies. For example, sudden jump in costs charged by a vendor in trouble would impact profitability and cash flow disproportionately across many industries, as would a bankruptcy of one of these big players – that would be like a mini bubble bursting, rippling across different industry segments. Is this likely? It’s certainly possible, so in that sense, there is a market risk that increases as this financial model is deployed, building in a bubble. It doesn’t seem very likely though – the big players, although have accelerated fast into the markets – seem very resilient so far. And in the enterprise space, if new technology disruptions occur like the current Salesforce and other vendors of cloud-based CRM taking over traditional CRM suppliers – they occur slowly and it becomes more a lifecycle adoption problem that companies plan for and manage (even if very painful).

What does seem likely is that companies will find themselves in a much more rigid cost structure than they are used to – locking in a cost to do business. In non-volatile conditions, it should work – companies will clearly drive productivity and efficiency savings to make up for the additional cost. But it does open questions about competitiveness and ability to handle volatility in a financial sense. It will be harder for companies to make corrections – they will have to cut deeper into their workforce or other costs to compensate for market changes than they are used to, they will have less control over contribution margins, profits and cash. Winners will be those that integrate and utilize the new functionality and cloud environment best – but that means those that integrate the systems and make them part of their business model best – paradoxically make them more dependent, not less.

So overall – maybe not a fiscal cliff – but it is a steep path next to a drop of some sort. It seems we have a period now of many companies adopting the same approach. So there is a risk of a dominant model for financing digitalisation emerging, as as concluded above, it does seem to share many characteristics that are common with a sector financial risk bubble.

As a result, we could be in for a period of relatively high cost structures despite acceleration of automation through AI, machine learning, robotics (both SW and physical robots) etc., so we end up with this strange effect of less jobs, seemingly increasing productivity in the companies, but no real outward impact on competitiveness, prices and so on.

Note , this is a review only of the financial model dominant around digital / Cloud IoT, not of the technologies themselves. I do not advocate we do not digitalize, or even slow down. However, we may need to think carefully about transition strategy – and what options and alternatives we have.

There are alternative strategies companies could take – I outlined one at end of “How do companies compete when Industry 4.0 hits?”

I would , as always , love to hear your comments and thoughts , if you get this far

How do companies compete when Industry 4.0 hits?

Future markets will be a combination of “dollar” and “non dollar” markets. Industry 4.0 / digitalization will lead to “dollar” markets shrinking but total markets, “dollar” + “non dollar” growing. Basically this is a sum of the last 2 blogs. .The final piece for me in this 3 part story is what happens to industrial companies and how will they thrive and compete – if Industry 4.0 is just going to accelerate the shrinking of “dollar” markets.

The answer for me is that value chains (the collections of customers and suppliers that form partnerships to compete) need to also to blend “dollar” and “non dollar” methods to supply goods and services to meet customer needs, reflecting the new reality of digital markets.

To explore and test this, I will set up a thought experiment to sum up the ideas about how the “dollar” markets will change due to digitalization, and then consider how we can blend “dollar” and “non dollar” in the supply as well as customer side. This thought experiment is ultra simplified to make a point, but could easily be scaled up to a complex model.

Consider a more traditional global setup of some market segment before widespread digitalisation. We will just think of two large regions far apart from each other ( Region 1 and Region 2). In each region, a Value Chain has emerged of linked producers to provide offerings to regional customer needs (Value chain 1 for Region 1 and Value chain 2 for Region 2). Its a global world, so some of the offerings from Value Chain 1 go to Region 2 and visa versa.

Scenario 1:

Global customer demand:

                          Region 1 | Region 2 | Total

Customer needs:     10    |     10       | 20

Of which are                

shared:                      ° — 5  — °        | 5

of which are                 

Unique:                     5      |       5        |  10

                                  In all 15 unique needs

Global production :

                      Value chain 1  Value chain 2

Number of offerings: 10    |      10       | 20

From other                  

value chain:              ° — 3 —-°       | 3

Of which are            

unique                         7    |      7       |  14

                              In all 17 unique offerings

Scenario 2: Along comes digitalization:

Number of customer

needs fulfilled

                       Region 1   | Region 2

Unique needs

fulfilled:             4 (of 5)    |   3 (of 5)

Shared needs            

fulfilled:               ° —   5    — °

Platform offerings   |—-12.—–I

                Value chain 1 | Value chain 2

Value chain          

offerings:          6           |      6  

Custom made            

offerings;                                1     

Needs not met: 1          |         1 (2 needs not met)

So what has happened ?

First – and this is a key part of any digitalization of a market – global “accessible” choice has increased . In the first scenario, there were 10 offerings on the market in each region . In the second there are 12. The platform dynamic of digitalization kicks in.

Next- the hidden downside outlined in the first blog – customers cannot fulfil all their needs as global “total” choice reduces. 3 needs cannot be met by the platform offerings. One is custom made (value justifies the increase in cost ) but 2 are withdrawn from the market. This is the effect mentioned in the first blog where companies can no longer cross subsidize offerings, so they take offering off the market – as cross-subsidized offerings option is stripped away due to the ability of digitalization to ensure customers just pay for that part they want.

As a result – finally – the dollar market offerings (and hence the “dollar” market itself) have shrunk as need and production become transparent. Each value chain has gone from 10 offerings each to 6 offerings each. Almost certainly due to higher competition and emerging transparency eliminating any offerings that are subsidized by other offerings.

Now nature (and markets) abhor a vacuum so something has to happen to meet the needs of customers – in reality they will not go unmet as illustrated in the model. The model is incomplete and something else must happen to allow needs to be met, even if value chains cannot afford to.

First a recap : Industy 4.0 will just make things worse – it is the enabler to shrinking “dollar” markets. Value chains will start by digital-enabled accelerated optimization of production and development – agile product development with increased software and simulation, additive manufacturing and other fast prototyping, fast Development and flexible manufacturing Technologies – leaner supply chains emerge to deliver only whats wanted – “pay as you use” efficient cloud based IT infrastructure will be even more widespread as flexibility at “efficient cost” spreads and companies need to transfer the “pay only for what I want” customer demand through the supply chain so we have “scale cost one to one to what is payed for” – automation of white collar and blue collar work accelerates with cheaper hyper flexible automation among others – “digital factories” emerge in all their possible forms – so factories are more & more decoupled from any particular design needing to be produced , and so on with all the drivers and buzz words around Industry 4.0. All these initiatives just accelerate the digitalization of the total market and shrink market size (for “dollar” part of markets).

All this implies a downward spiral on the value chains that in turn deprive customers at a total market level of fufilling needs whilst they are being drowned in choice driven by global platforms.

However, previously, we suggested we will move to a situation where the total market would be a “dollar market” + a “non dollar” market. Customers will access value by combining both markets, so the “dollar market” could shrink but total (dollar + non dollar) market could still grow. Customers will not be limited to paying the value chain – they can access sharing economy solutions – maybe also carve out and access only part of the value chain and do the rest themselves – or other options opened up via full digitalization.

This same dynamic, however, is also available to industrial companies (after all one persons supplier is another persons customer and value chains are just collections of customers and suppliers that form partnerships to compete with other value chains )

This leads to an obvious answer in how will we compete when Industry 4.0 hits: value chains need to also be made up of dollar and non dollar means of production as they transition via Industry 4.0 to a digital world. 

So how does dollar & non dollar blended means of production work?

Today we are already seeing some elements emerging, building on business models that have been part of the Internet subculture (like the open source movement) since its birth.

We have seen the fruits of this social / sharing economy subculture moving into industry, with for example, open source being a part of the corporate infrastructure (eg think apache servers). We also have “old” stories from corporate business of how sharing economies could work for large investments / capital expenditure (as opposed to end user sharing of their personal investments like cars or houses), such as corporate jets being shared between Customers (Netjet). 

From this we start to see new patterns. Cloud platform houses that serve large companies are building open source into their offerings, releasing more code to open source and developing and changing their offerings by combining own development with shared and open source development – building customers into the development requests and outputs, much like open source. An example of this is microsoft Azure platform with 1000’s (ok maybe 100’s) of tools accessible – many being open source and much of the code also released – and the development also run in an agile and ”open source” like way with customers. Not sure if it will be successful but its a serious attempt to blend dollar & non-dollar markets and if they reflect this blend in price & value of offering, it could work. It certainly is a very fast dynamic platform – at odds perhaps with Microsoft traditional corporate image.

Another example is emergence of ventures trying to offer capacity on 3D printers to others and I’m sure many other types of industrial asset sharing ventures will follow (another prediction – don’t forget to allocate a fractional value of your company shares to me if this idea is new to you and you start up a venture from it) – so a company can share the cost of invested capital by sharing capacity.  

As we move to “digital” products (discussed before) and Industry 4.0 technologies , this type of industrial sharing will become easier and be more and more frequent. We can see with the emergence of shared 3D printing capacity ideas (additive manufacturing) , the key is to solve guarantees of data security – but this is already happening. Then companies can offer, for example, “shared” spare capacity in the same way we share car capacity in say “Go More” or houses in “Airbnb”. This capability to share will be accelerated by Industry 4.0 trends that have a tendency to move the value to the digital part of production and design.

This sharing can easily be extended. As manufacturing designs become digital, it is easy to see that some design templates will become public, others may be available in some kind of libraries at significantly lower prices. Companies wanting to meet customer needs, but needing to keep profit and margins, could start blending offerings – combining their own designs and using their manufacturing capacity and supply chains to also make “free” or shared designs to enable wider offerings – or using their assets to make products for other value chains. We see the release of IP from Tesla playing directly into this arena. We also see libraries appearing on the internet for devices that can be created for 3D printing – its not hard to imagine these designs also encompassing more industrial areas rather than fun things for the home – a quick scan of some of the serious enthusiast areas shows this is not a long way from this (browse thingiverse or grabcad if you want)

So what will we compete on in the future?

In the digital future, customers will be able to get their products from multiple supply chains with help of platforms to get best cost. However, some companies and value chains will be a much better “experience” than others – they will claim higher “non dollar” value through ratings, reputation and other social/shared currencies – and these will become key to success – both for their financial credibility in the “dollar” world and success overall. The future will go to those that compete in both “dollar” and “non dollar” economies. 

This will require excellence in two arenas. First, those that can blend the two worlds into their value chains to ensure the correct blend of own offerings with own value add, combined with shared/free offerings of the “non dollar” market to ensure the best value to cost possible. Second those that can create experiences to transfer this value to customers and achieve highest social / shared economy Capital.

When will we start trading in Tripadvisor ratings?

Or when are our Internet platform powerhouses like Google, facebook, Airbnb, Uber, twitter , Amazon, Trip advisor going to become our new financial industry giants of the “non dollar” economy?

As a result, going forward we will view markets and market size as a sum of “dollar” and “non dollar” markets.

Previously , I outlined a picture of how Industry 4.0 will shrink “dollar” markets – although “non dollar” value will emerge and to some extent fill this gap. For shorthand – I’ll call the world of money the “dollar” markets or ” dollar” world and the social / sharing world the “non dollar” markets or “non dollar” world.

This time I want to explore this “non dollar” value and “the new gangs of the digital era” that control it. As a result, I will push the idea that these are the start of a new type of financial industry that will emerge to support the “non dollar” markets. (By “new gangs” I mean internet platform powerhouses like Amazon, Google,Tripadvisor , Facebook and so on).  

A warning though – this blog is longer and more speculative than the last.

These new gangs of the digital era give access to , and control, the new currencies of the digital age , the currencies of “social” and “sharing” economies ( reputation, followers, likes , ratings, reviews , ..), as effectively as the financial industry control & gives access to money in markets today. Both financial Institutions & these “new gangs” , on the whole, do not directly make the things we want and need , but without them , their platforms & related services , we cannot operate & do our business in the non dollar or dollar markets.

As we begin to place real value on the social & sharing economies emerging in the digital world – the roles the platforms play , it seems to me , look more & more like the roles of financial institutions. Hence the phrase “new gangs of the digital world” taking their cut and charging protection money – a slightly biased view of the financial sector living off others wealth creation work. I understand the argument that these are also essential enablers to wealth creation – but I’ll stick to my metaphor for now. 

It is perhaps too early to confirm that we are seeing the emergence of a parallel financial market infrastructure for the digital world, supporting the “non dollar” markets, but we can build up a hypothesis based on analogies to the “dollar” world and use these to predict trends in the “non dollar” world. If we see these trends, then it goes a long way to support the prediction that going forward we will need to view markets and market size as a sum of “dollar” and “non dollar” markets.

If we go back to the USA before the greenback we know today existed ( the story of USA currency before the greenback taken from NPR, Planet Money podcast #421) -we had banks in each city or region issueing their own dollar notes – each note having different relative values in shops based on factors such as how close to the bank you were, the percieved reputation of the bank and so on. Think, for example, of different reviews in different platforms – do you trust the review of a hotel in some web travel site you have never heard of, or do you trust the overall review status af Tripadvisor. It might be that the website review is completely trustworthy to some group of people, but you still discount it in your head – in the same way a shop would discount a dollar from an unknown bank – and for similar reasons – you have no basis on which to place that trust and so you don’t .

Today we are seeing an emergence of agreement or at least “customs” about how to handle things like reputation , likes , reviews and so on. When we see a review or a trending rank for example , we have a picture in our head what this means eg. a review rating is , if in a 5 star format, the aggregation of many peoples opinions who are genuine users of the goods or service in question , and who are not connected to the seller in any way. There is no place where this is written down as the law , but platforms offering reviews converge towards this, as the “custom” is established, and people place their trust in that custom . And those places we think follow best this custom and have scale of numbers (lots of reviews, with well regulated process, as perceived for Amazon or Tripadvisor ) get our highest trust. (This, as an aside, is also close to the explanation why we put value on Money at the end of the day – NPR Planet Money #423). All this is very similar to how a shop would trust a large well financed bank with many customers that is nearby, over one they did not know very well.

To see the power of these customs , it is interesting to see how Facebook makes world news when it is revealed that their ranked trending information is subject to editorial oversight and is not pure trend data . It probably makes sense they should do this , but it is not what we thought was “Custom” so it becomes news , reflecting our unease , even if, as far as I know, no one at all thinks Facebook has manipulated any information in a “bad” way. But maybe they could, and thats enough to undermine a little of our trust.

Back to banks of old- after a while there was the emergence of conversion books as travel & trade grew. How can one shop value a dollar from a particular bank it had never heard of – books were published to help this – complex tables based on how far the bank was , away, reputation and so on. Essentially this was a formalization of informal rules and customs, shops were using to judge the value of a dollar, to enable conversion between different Institutes offering the dollar. We are seeing first attempts of formalised “books” now in some “non dollar” currencies – in particular reputation reviews. Some are trying to build sites that can take reputation from different platforms – attempting to enable people to transfer reputation. Its hard to see these first attempts working, partly I think due to the value of the non dollar currencies in question are not yet trustworthy or consistent enough, and partly because the internet is a place of monopolies, and if 90% of all banking is in one bank (think Tripadvisor) – you don’t need to bother with conversion books. But this is changing, so expect to see more attempts going forward.

So what is down the line ? I don’t think one replaces the other – we will operate with both dollar & non dollar currencies although conversion between the two is not obvious at this time. I am sure some will occur eg I can see ”reviews” and some types of “rating” having some conversion behaviour as they are discrete (ie separate from the object being reviewed and rated) a bit like discrete money units, but its hard to see how you can convert for example , reputation & then reduce your own reputation as a result of “selling” reputation. However, its not so hard to see a trade & markets where different types of “non dollar” exist together with “dollar” & also not hard to see that “value” in the eyes of customers can be a sum of “dollar”& “non dollar” values.

So to predictions

Formalization of trading rules & legal frameworks to handle disputes & reduce “fake currency “. This seems one direction for “non dollar” markets. Already now, we can forge identities & personalities, we can create false follows or false hits to make sure we have presence in a particular “non dollar ” market (think manipulating to push up a google search ranking or fake follows to be impressive on Twitter ). Also people or companies that are deliberately attacked to ensure “bad reputation” or “bad reviews”.. Or the company itself can manipulate its own system. These things are beginning to have significant real word value and financial consequences. In AirBnB , we have two way reputation, so unless you have a history, some rooms will not let you book them, a top Tripadvisor restaurant can have huge increase in bookings, and so on. Today we are at the mercy of the platform company and how it decides to police its own world. When change occurs – it is mass public outcry that forces the platform to take action (think Facebook “panic button” in UK). But today , essentially the platform company decides and no arbitration. Its hard to see this as sustainable, people will demand more fair rules and independent arbitration , as in financial markets. We already see the start of establishment & legal reaction, with for example UK Competition & Market authority investigation into fake reviews in Tripadvisor and Amazon, and with different legislation at local level impacting AirBnB and Uber (eg New York conflict with AirBnB, Uber and Austin).

Emergence of “standard” currencies.The greenbacks & Euro’s of social & sharing economies. Today a review in one platform can be completely different than from another, in the way the review is done (subjective opinion from third party, paid opinion, advertising designed as review and so on). Linked to reviews are ratings. Ratings are more & more valuable – we rate restaurants on Trip advisor. We trust those ratings as honest – now Trip advisor can issue “badges of excellence” and restaurants can then display these in their promotions . But not all ratings are equal. Try giving a bad review on “Trust pilot” – a company that provides ratings to help reassure people if a website is reliable – especially for making purchases. Here the company rules are different and they reserve the right to delete the review if it is not provable to their satisfaction – higher quality ratings? or serving the interest of the companies paying to use Trust pilot. Not sure , but hey, the company can decide its own rules, so whats the problem?.

The point is, we know (or are learning fast ) that a review is not a review . We assign reputation & trust to one source & discount heavily another – in the same way shops of old assigned value to dollars in the story above. We will see the different “non dollar” currency customs strengthen over time and less tolerance by people when they find out a company does not follow that custom. Eventually this will give rise to a “standard” for that currency that people will want enforced. Personally I think for reviews – this standard will be like an “Amazon” standard for many non food consumer goods or “Tripadvisor” standard for hotels, restaurants and leisure activities- but I’m sure there will be more than one in each type of “non dollar” currency . There is nothing in the history of the “dollar” world to suggest nice simple global currencies or rules – More a slow , messy & painful journey with many currencies and many different ways to run markets , just like the financial markets.

Market places to trade & manage trade .Maybe the real value of Tripadvisor in the future is to be the gold standard review trading platform (or marketplace) for all reviews tied to Hotels, restaurants & leisure activities. Anyone needing this type of review goes via here ( trivago , expedia and so on ). Amazon could be another for some consumer goods categories. I am not sure what trading means in “non dollar” currencies – but we can speculate (this is only based on my imagination ) – for example a rating of a restaurant is a lot like a share value. It reflects a consumer assessment of value , in the same way a share price assesses financial value. It varies over time reflecting changing experience, consumer taste , and fashion. It also creates herd behaviour -people tend to go to the top rated . Trip advisor could go down the route of a monopoly bank , or it could also open up its platform & start producing “review” information, trends / performance over time, and any number of “non dollar” financial data that could be used if we wanted, to complement financial data on a company. It also stands alone, as many hoteIs, restaurants, shops, are private so financial data /trading is not public but reviews are available. I have not heard of it yet, but someone in the financial sector must be using this info to help analysis of shares & stocks to give trading recommendations ! (and if not , then please send me a cut of your increased profits when you do, as originator of the idea) – it seems a natural step. Then what – trading in Tripadvisor ratings? – I can definitely see a bank landing money based on strong long term good review ratings – and so we have conversion between dollar and non dollar markets.

As this blog is long enough , I have not tried to explore parallels for “follow” , “like” , search ratings and other “non dollar” areas. But the same thinking can apply – we know number of “follows” and trends in “follow” have real value. Number of views and likes on YouTube already make a few people rich, Buzzfeed is all about finding video clips and other stuff that “sell” and go viral on social media , and so on.

Thoughts & comments welcome

Njal

(NOTE: the views expressed here are my own and do not represent the views of the company I work for)

Will Industry 4.0 shrink the market size for all markets?

Or put another way – is it inevitable that markets as we understand them will shrink in their “dollar” value as we go through the digital industrial revolution (although the “actual” value market as seen from consumer may not shrink and even grow).

This , of course, would have major consequences for things like stock markets – suggesting a continued future of volatility – as markets continuously correct themselves to accommodate this shrinkage.

Digitalization of the newspaper & music industries have decimated these markets and related markets such as Tv and film are under massive pressures and could go the same way.

Is this also our futures in the Industry segments so eager to embrace Industry 4.0?

When newspapers first faced the digitalisation of their markets -the assumption was this was a zero sum game and the market tommorow was the same as today -the cake stayed the same – the digital disruption would just reshuffle the deck of winners & losers .

This seemed an eminently reasonable logic. The first wave of digital transformation was a step change in productivity – elimination of the whole layer of print production -journalists could type & then digitally send to automated print anywhere in the world – more content, cheaper production . Lets do more.

In hindsight , we could not have been more wrong – the cake has shrunk radically – maybe by a factor of 10 – and it was a bit more than a reshuffle of players sharing the pie – more like the pie shrunk , the smaller pie was shared among the players and then a whole new group of gangs moved into the neighborhood and demanded protection money (google , adblock + and the like).

It is easy to explain this as a market specific event – but what if this is an inevitable consequence of digitalization , the only question is how long it will take? 

Music again seems a similar dynamic -maybe the pie is reduced by a factor of 3, not 10, as we figure out how to shore up the hemourage that is pirate copying and replace it with streaming – since music does not have the double wammy of newspapers, that is both customer & advertising revenue collapse – but otherwise a lot of parallels. TV & film as a total market seems a little more stable, but many cracks are appearing, like un-bundling of channels and streaming platforms , also wide spread pirating these media, and social media alternatives.

We can make a long list of reasons why what happened to newspapers is unique to them and digitalization of the whole market just exposed a flawed market. But we are, perhaps, just kidding ourselves and digitization of an entire market – once it has reached a certain critical mass – is fundamentally tied to the way markets work and the result is that the total market size will shrink. 

Maybe the only difference between the newspaper industry and other markets is the speed it happened – they are the equivalent to the fruit fly – the fast moving consumer goods of the industrial world, in terms of seeing the effect of digitalization. Its entire market segment was one of the first where digitalization could occur across all elements of the value chain, from the product being 100% digital, consumers being able to consume digitally and customize their product , to advertisers being able to advertise digitally, to content able to be un-bundled, re-bundled & distributed digitally and to parts of the market changing to a sharing or free economy (eg news blogs).

We should treat the newspaper market like a time-lapsed video of what will happen in other markets in the future, a fruit fly experiment of Industry 4.0. Something that works at a speed that alIows us to observe the entire life cycle. We can then look at our own industries to see if we can find markers that point in the same direction.

Given this is business mangement & not a scientific discipline it will be more like a Greek philosopher extrapolating how the world works from an armchair rather than data – but today I’m sure someone will figure out a way to verify it if so inclined.

Lets build our simple newpaper thought experiment: We have 1m customers who buy newspapers at $1 each. We also have 1000 advertisers willing to pay $2000 each . So our newspaper has an income of $3m.

Along comes digitalization and explodes the access to the newspaper content. Now we have 10m people who can access and want to read some or all content, and 10,000 advertisers attracted to this crowd. 

BUT – now our customers are willing to spend only $0.01 on content (maybe premium subscribers – rest will skim for free). Our advertisers are also now using targeted adverts via likes google and via adblock+ and in effect only willing to pay $20 each on average. Suddenly our newspaper is looking at $0.3m.

Whats happened? – our customers can start choosing to pay only if they want the content, and only that sliver of content that is of interest. Maybe they buy an app. that helps them find what they want – or get it for free – with a few paying for premium service (our neighbourhood gang effect). Maybe they get part of the news via social media and blogs. Maybe they pay a little bit in several places to get their favorite stuff directly (I subscribe to 3 online speciality publications – rest is “free” podcasts and news articles online – CNN & BBC for me).

On the other side, the newspapers have to cut down drastically in content & staff – gone are the too expensive investigations and the idiosyncratic articles – and they find out what people really like from them. To make this pay, the more limited content is then packaged and distributed out into as many forms as possible (online, hard copy, apps., tweets, resold to other channels …) and supplemented by cheap 3rd party content.

Finally our friendly gangs move in from out of town (no prior interest in news needed – but rule access from anything to anything in the digital space) – making it so easy for customers to find what they want, advertisers to get to who they want and offering newspapers access to a much wider world. Everything with a tiny cut to them along the way. 

This opens up for some interesting potential trends:The “insurance” model of diverse businesses is undermined – its no longer possible to have many products (different types of own content by wide range of journalists) where popular content cross-subsidizes minority “products”. Only popular content can survive.

Content also starts to survive by becoming highly specialized so the few with interest pay the price (handcraft prices).

Or the newpaper focuses on producing a narrow but mass market appeal content and distributing it in many other outlets – eg weather news. 

Platforms also emerge controlling large parts of the consumer space (winner takes all) but rarely from incumbents and always a radically simplified cost model often building on high repetition globally of (cheap) successful own formats and / or heavy use of social content or advertiser friendly. Newspapers try and survive also building platforms mixing own and 3rd party content. In other industries (eg Netflix for film/ tv) we see a potential for a few winners to take all with this – but newspapers seem stubbornly fragmented and regional, so never getting the scale.

And customers ? yes choice explodes – but many special interest areas suddenly require separate payments , apps for access, online subscriptions, direct payment for single content streaming.  Choice of quality products may even be going down (fewer content widely repeated) and cost to the consumer may not reduce as much as thought once all the small payments are added up (our “protection gangs” are not for free at the end of the day).

Does this mean consumers live in a poorer world? not necessarily – as the third element emerges (besides professional content and platforms ) – that of a social media and sharing economy alternative. Blogs and hobbyists – maybe not all be for free, but willing to work and share closer to “at cost” , also building quality and credibility, valueing reputation and widespread visibility (lots of followerers) i.e. other currencies emerge other than just the “dollar” currency.

The effect is the “dollar” market shrinks – but the actual accessible “value” market may indeed grow.  It is this conclusion that is at the heart of our thought experiment – and these trends and conclusions have a potential to be true across all markets that begin to digitalize at scale across their value chains – ultimately also industrial markets – causing all “dollar” markets to shrink but not necessarily the “value” market.

To give an example – lets run a thought experiment of the future in discrete manufacturing. We see a significant scale up in 3D printing and simulation tools. As we get closer to 3D printing for manufacturing (additive manufacturing-AM), Roland Berger (the consultant company) suggests that mechanical engineering will start to look like software engineering. Designs will be done virtually, and straight to 3D printed products. I don’t see this as universal but even if not by AM, manufacturing will be flexible and able to mass customize more readily. Factories will be able to produce a much wider range of goods from digital inputs (designs and all associated info to produce them). More simple areas will automate the design process completely based on inputs from consumers (Customers simulate what they want in easy ways & all design elements and info is created automatically thats needed to produce them – then “generic” factories produce the design from the data). Once this occurs – the deep technical knowledge driving cost advantage will erode, as we have seen in our newspaper thought experiment. Factories don’t have to be tied to any one company – they can be platforms to produce many things at need. Designs are now all digital. Piracy means even the best can be copied. Social / hobbyists will create their own digital solutions and share them via social / sharing economies that will be as good as company offerings and consumers can also choose these and get them made anywhere. I can go on . Conclusion of this version of the thought experiment will be similar to the newspaper industry.  Variation and availability from the “dollar” market will have to reduce – less money – focus on only what sells best – replication across platforms (“global template products”?) , consumers get less choice in core templates/types of products, but can mass customize these template products to their hearts content . The sharing economy will take up some of the slack and the overall effect may be the market itself does not shrink so much (or grow – who knows) in eyes of the consumer , but the “dollar” size goes Down.

Can we reverse this – no. The old truth is you can’t stop progress. I would even argue companies will pour money into being more digital and accelerate the trend even though they start to see there will be an overall reduced market. This is because, in the digital world , a new type of winner is possible – the one that takes it all. We see the mega platforms of Google, Facebook, Amazon and Apple seemingly being able to continue to leverage their power. So any sane CEO will push hard to make sure its their company that tries to take it all. Its like we have a digital lottery where the illusion is we can all walk away multi-millionaires – even when all logic and math show that statistically you are wasting your money. As long as we can point out now and again one winner – we forget the many who lost.

Will we see this soon? – unlikely – as it starts to hit – it will also enable under-developed markets like Africa to accelerate as prices drop and accessibility goes up – and this will maintain markets for a while, if nothing else. Also many markets have very long life cycles (eg. we don’t replace housing stock that fast – and renovation and retro-fit also is not always that fast).

Thoughts & comments welcome

Njal

(NOTE: the views expressed here are my own and do not represent the views of the company I work for)